Escaping the Housing Trap by Charles L. Marohn Jr. & Daniel Herriges

Escaping the Housing Trap by Charles L. Marohn Jr. & Daniel Herriges

Author:Charles L. Marohn, Jr. & Daniel Herriges [Marohn, Charles L. & Herriges, Daniel]
Language: eng
Format: epub
ISBN: 9781394198306
Publisher: Wiley
Published: 2024-04-23T00:00:00+00:00


Homevoters versus the Growth Machine (Spoiler: They Both Win)

It would be too simplistic to suggest there is no countervailing force at work here. There is: it's just that the status quo of growth politics ends up being a compromise largely acceptable to many interest groups—all except those who need housing to be cheaper.

For decades, two theories have dominated the academic study of how local political power operates. One theory, associated with the political scientist William Fischel (2005), is the “homevoter hypothesis.” Fischel argues that homeowners whose primary interest is in maintaining their property values are a powerful and often dominant interest group in city politics.

The other theory, associated with sociologist Harvey Molotch, is that of the “growth machine.” Molotch wrote in 1988 that “virtually all U.S. cities are dominated by a small, parochial elite whose members have business or professional interests that are linked to local development and growth. These elites use public authority and private power as a means to stimulate economic development and thus enhance their own local business interests” (Molotch 1988).

A coalition resembling Molotch's growth machine wields significant political power in many cities large and small. Real estate developers are often major campaign donors. Money buys influence, but there is also a more basic convergence of interests. City officials want a tax base to fund the services they provide. Developers create that tax base.

Most “neighborhood defender” development opponents identify something like the growth machine as their bête noire. “Citizens versus developers” is the narrative of choice of many, perhaps most, of the NIMBY contingent.

What is not true is that the interests of the growth machine stand in straightforward opposition to the interests of homeowners. These are both powerful constituencies, and the system we have is basically a compromise that works for both of them. If it didn't, it probably wouldn't endure.

To be clear, homevoters and growth advocates have genuine, sincere disagreements and fight bitterly over specific projects. It's just that the system as a whole ends up basically acceptable to both sets of interests.

The big development interests get the ability to build at large scales in specific, limited contexts: suburban subdivisions and large-scale urban infill in the minority of places where it is allowed. They get a land-use regime that, as we discussed in Chapter 5, provides ample opportunity for speculation and windfall gains. They also get an often convoluted regulatory system in which they have an advantage as insiders.

Entrenched developers don't need or necessarily want to maximize housing production region-wide; if anything, the resulting abundance and competition would cut into their profit margins. The developers most likely to be part of a politically connected growth machine occupy a privileged position as insiders in a sector with substantial barriers to entry.

The homevoters get their own neighborhoods mostly insulated from change (though the most ideological opponents of development in general may end up disappointed). They get a substantial amount of input and deference in the political process. And overall housing scarcity means that they get to reap the benefits of home value appreciation, as surely as land speculators in the real estate industry.



Download



Copyright Disclaimer:
This site does not store any files on its server. We only index and link to content provided by other sites. Please contact the content providers to delete copyright contents if any and email us, we'll remove relevant links or contents immediately.